What Is Marginalism in Microeconomics, and Why Is It Important?

Sean Ross is a strategic adviser at 1031x.com, Investopedia contributor, and the founder and manager of Free Lances Ltd.

Updated August 23, 2023 Reviewed by Reviewed by Erika Rasure

Erika Rasure is globally-recognized as a leading consumer economics subject matter expert, researcher, and educator. She is a financial therapist and transformational coach, with a special interest in helping women learn how to invest.

Fact checked by Fact checked by Yarilet Perez

Yarilet Perez is an experienced multimedia journalist and fact-checker with a Master of Science in Journalism. She has worked in multiple cities covering breaking news, politics, education, and more. Her expertise is in personal finance and investing, and real estate.

Marginalism describes both an economical method of analysis and a theory of value. According to this theory, individuals make economic decisions "on the margin." That is, value is determined by how much additional utility an extra unit of a good or service provides.

It would be difficult to overstate how important this concept is to contemporary economic understanding. The development of marginal theory is commonly referred to as the Marginalist Revolution and is seen as the dividing line between classical and modern economics.

Key Takeaways

The Marginalist Revolution

Adam Smith was the founding father of economic science, but even he was perplexed by real economic value: Why do people sometimes value non-essential goods more than essential goods? A paradox in value appeared to exist that couldn't be rationally explained. This became known as the paradox of "value in use" versus "value in exchange."

The best-known example of this is the diamond-water paradox. Even though diamonds serve no vital purpose, and water is essential to human life, individual diamonds are far more valuable than individual units of water. On the surface, it seems like water should be worth more.

Independently and almost simultaneously, three economists solved this puzzle in the 1870s: William Stanley Jevons, Carl Menger, and Leon Walras. They suggested that individual consumers don't choose between all of the world's water versus all of the world's diamonds; obviously, they would pick water if given that choice.

Marginal utility is most often broken down into positive marginal utility, negative marginal utility, and zero marginal utility.

Rather, individuals pick between increments of a good. They separately determine the worth of having one additional unit of water or one additional unit of diamonds. These individual choices are made on the margin.

Ostensibly, water is far easier to come by, and most people already have access to enough water to fulfill their wants. In these conditions, the value of that extra unit of water is relatively low. This is not usually the case with diamonds because diamonds are expensive to buy.

Of course, an incredibly thirsty man in the desert might value that extra unit of water more than an extra diamond. This is the difference between total utility and marginal utility.

Why Is Marginalism Important?

The development of marginalist theory helped to better explain human rationality, human action, subjective valuation, and efficient market prices. In doing so, marginal analysis opened the door for a new era in microeconomics.

Marginal utility can be difficult to gauge as it is hard to assess how much utility an individual gets from one more unit of a good or service, especially since this measurement is different for every individual. This concept is laid out in the law of diminishing marginal utility, which states that as consumption increases, utility decreases.

For example, if someone is craving a cheeseburger, they may be willing to pay extra for a cheeseburger if they are really hungry, let's say, $10. Now, after the first cheeseburger, the same individual might still be hungry but think spending $10 on another cheeseburger is too much.

They would, however, buy another cheeseburger if it cost $5 instead of $10. This law of diminishing marginal utility shows that the value of a cheeseburger is less once an individual increases their consumption of it.

Marginalism helps businesses price their goods accurately as it gives an insight into what a consumer values. The price decreases as consumption increases and vice versa. Price and quantity, therefore, have an inverse relationship.

What Is Marginalism in Neoclassical Economics?

Marginalism in Neoclassical economics is the theory that people make decisions based on margins, such as marginal utility and marginal cost. For example, a person would choose to spend money on a good or service dependent on the marginal utility they receive from consuming one more unit of that good or service.

What Is the Marginalist Theory of Production?

The marginalist theory of production only works in a perfect market so it is primarily theoretical than practical. It states that the amount paid into each component in the production process equals the value of the extra output the component of production generates.

What Is the Law of Diminishing Marginal Utility?

The law of diminishing marginal utility states that the more of a good or service a consumer consumes, the satisfaction (utility) that they derive from it decreases. For example, if a person eats a cheeseburger because they are hungry, they will be satisfied. If they eat a second cheeseburger, their satisfaction will not be as high as from the first cheeseburger: the law of diminishing marginal utility.

The Bottom Line

Marginalism seeks to understand the additional value a consumer gains from an additional unit of a good or service and how their purchasing decisions are affected by that.

Businesses can use marginalism to correctly price their products to ensure that they are at a value that people will continue to buy or even buy in the first place. It is an important area of economics that tries to understand the behavior of individuals.

Related Articles

What Does Accord and Satisfaction Mean in a Legal Contract?

Rent Seeking

What Is Rent Seeking in Economics, and What Are Some Examples?

Economic Equilibrium: A condition or state in which economic forces are balanced.

Economic Equilibrium: How It Works, Types, in the Real World

Elastic

Elasticity: What It Means in Economics, Formula, and Examples

Isoquant Curve

Isoquant Curve in Economics Explained: Properties and Formula

Cans Of Cola

What Is a Rival Good? Difference From Non-Rival Good, With Examples Partner Links Related Terms

Accord and satisfaction is a legal contract whereby two parties agree to discharge a claim for an amount other than the original amount of the claim.

Rent seeking is defined as any practice in which an entity aims to increase its wealth without making any contribution to the wealth or benefit of society

Economic equilibrium is a condition or state in which economic forces are balanced.

Elasticity is an economic term that describes the responsiveness of one variable to changes in another. It commonly refers to how demand changes in response to price.

The isoquant curve is a graph used in the study of microeconomics that charts all inputs that produce a specified level of output.

A rival good is a product or service that can only be consumed by one user or a limited number of users, potentially creating consumer demand and driving up its price.

Investopedia is part of the Dotdash Meredith publishing family.

We Care About Your Privacy

We and our 100 partners store and/or access information on a device, such as unique IDs in cookies to process personal data. You may accept or manage your choices by clicking below, including your right to object where legitimate interest is used, or at any time in the privacy policy page. These choices will be signaled to our partners and will not affect browsing data.

We and our partners process data to provide:

Store and/or access information on a device. Use limited data to select advertising. Create profiles for personalised advertising. Use profiles to select personalised advertising. Create profiles to personalise content. Use profiles to select personalised content. Measure advertising performance. Measure content performance. Understand audiences through statistics or combinations of data from different sources. Develop and improve services. Use limited data to select content. List of Partners (vendors)